To My Readers,
Pasted-in below: Another key blog-entry, from elsewhere, that I think you will want to know about.
For Humanity,
“GLOBAL STRATEGIC HYPOTHESES: In this blog, we have held that what F.E.D.
terms ‘technodepreciation’
-- the technological obsolescence self-depreciation continually ongoing within the total social fixed capital -- i.e., the self-devaluation
of capital-value, ‘the self-negation
of capital as capital’, is the fatal
flaw of the capitalist system -- is the key to the
historical dialectic of capital, to the ever-intensifying global crises of
capitalism, and to the lawful destiny of the capitalist/world market system as
a whole.
We
have held that the process of ‘technodepreciation’
is the key to the cause
of the turning point from the global ascendance phase to the global descendance
phase of the capitals system, as an historical totality.
We
have held that the emerging ruling class consciousness of the process of ‘technodepreciation’, ever-worsening in
its consequences for their interests as the competitive accumulation of capital
proceeds, is the psychohistorical cause of the degeneration of the
descendant phase capitalist ruling class into anti-progress, anti-productive forces growth,
pro-contracted social
reproduction, ‘‘‘humanocidal’’’ ideologies -- which are both anti-science, and
anti-technology, to the extent that science and technology are used to advance
the social forces of production, to raise human living standards, versus when
science and technology for police state surveillance, for preparation for war,
for actual wars, and for ever the “innovation” of ever more destructive weapons
of mass destruction.
Ruling
class fear of the de facto overthrow of their power by capital[ist] ‘technodepreciation’ is, we have held, especially
the motive force, for their planned ‘humanocide’, and for their already globally underway ‘stealth eugenics genocides’, with
regard to the ruling core of the descendance phase capitalist ruling class -- in
particular, the petroleum/finance plutocracy, centered around the
Rockefeller ‘ “Eu”-genics ‘ “Family” Political Machine [the Rockefeller
Foundations; predominant influence within Exxon-Mobil, J. P. Morgan Chase Bank, Citibank, Bank of America,
New York Council on Foreign Relations, Trilateral Commission, Federal Reserve, U.
S. Federal Government Executive Branch, UN, IMF, World Bank, ITO, AMA, Southern
Baptist Church, etc.] with regard to their fear of the world-market negation of their petroleum
industry capital that would be caused by the advent of fusion power.
That
is, we have held that ruling class consciousness of ‘technodepreciation’ is the psychohistorical
cause of the “Eu”-genocidal ruling
class ideologies of their descendance phase -- ‘‘‘humanocidal’’’ ideologies of ‘Capitalist Anti-Capitalism’,
of ‘Human Anti-Humanism’,
and of ‘Anti-Marxian Marxianism’,
i.e., to the turn of the strategy of that ruling class toward the goals of
productive forces growth reversal,
hence of “95% global population
reduction”/ destruction,
publicly “justified” on the basis of pseudo-ecological excuses, which make that
ruling class a threat to the survival of the working/“middle” class, i.e., of the
growing majority of humanity, globally: a
threat to the survival of global humanity; :
a threat to the survival of the human species entire.
Because
the dialectical-scientific work of Karl Marx, toward elucidating “the
[political-]economic law of motion of modern society”, is the starting point of
the theory of capitalism’s developing self-demise presented herein, it would be
right to ask “¿What does Karl
Marx have to say on the subject of the process that we name ‘technodepreciation’?
The
purpose of this series is to address that question.
Readers,
. . .
. . .
Part
1. Marx on ‘Technodepreciation’.
Introductory Passages.
Let
us begin our examination and consideration of Marx’s writings, bearing on the
topic of ‘technodepreciation’,
with Marx’s general statement, from the «Grundrisse», on
the ‘meta-dynamics’ of the self-imposed demise of that historically-specific human
social system founded, and foundered, upon “the capital relation” as
predominating “social relation of production” --
“...the development of the
productive forces
brought about by the historical development of capital itself, when it reaches a certain stage, suspends [i.e., “«aufheben»”-negates -- M.D.] the self-realization of capital itself, instead of positing it.
“Beyond a certain point, the development of the
powers of production
becomes a barrier for capital; hence the capital relation a barrier for the development of the productive powers
of labor.”
“When it has reached this point, capital, i.e. wage labor, enters into the same relation towards
the development of social wealth and of the forces of production as the guild system, serfdom, slavery, and is necessarily stripped off as a fetter.”
“The
last form of servitude assumed by human activity, that of wage labor on one side, capital on the other, is thereby cast off like
a skin, and this casting-off is itself the result of the mode of production corresponding to
capital; the material and mental conditions of the negation of wage labor and of capital, themselves
already the negation
of earlier forms of unfree
social production, are themselves the result of its production
process.”
“The growing
incompatibility between the productive development of society and its
hitherto existing relations of production
expresses itself in bitter contradictions, crises, spasms.”
“The violent
destruction of capital, not by relations external to it, but rather
as a condition of its
self-preservation, is the most striking form in which advice is given it to be gone
and to give room to a higher
state of social production...
“Hence the highest
development of productive power
together with the greatest expansion of existing wealth
will coincide with depreciation of capital,
degradation of the laborer,
and a most straitened exhaustion
of his vital powers.”
“These contradictions lead to explosions, cataclysms, crises, in which, by momentaneous suspension of all labor
and annihilation of a great portion of capital
the latter is violently
reduced to the point where it can go on fully employing its productive powers without committing suicide.”
“Yet these regularly recurring catastrophes lead to their repetition on a higher scale
and finally to its violent
overthrow.” [pp. 749-750].
[Karl Marx, Grundrisse: Foundations of the Critique of
Political Economy (Rough Draft), translated by Martin
Nicolaus, Penguin Books [Middlesex: 1973], emphases
added by
M.D.].
The
above passage does not address ‘technodepreciation’
directly.
But
it does address ‘‘‘the depreciation / destruction of capital[-value]’’’ as an
element of the “crises” of the capitals-system -- those “regularly
recurring catastrophes” [like the one that Terran humanity is presently suffering through --
openly, ever since 2007 C.E.], that “lead to their repetition on a higher scale
and finally to its [i.e., to the capital-relation’s -- M.D.] violent overthrow [of
“the capital relation” as predominating human production-relation -- M.D.].”
One
would hope that the violence of the predicted “violent overthrow” of “the
capital-relation” as predominating “social relation of production” can be
mitigated in a world polity that has achieved some advancing degree of formal,
representative democracy, as Marx too envisioned, in a latter statement. But that remains to be seen.
‘Technodepreciation’ of capital
-- “destruction”, “depreciation”, and “annihilation” of older capital-value, of
past-accumulated fixed capital-value -- is caused by the growth of the social
forces of production, also driven by the capital-relation -- by what amounts,
in its most general result, to the growth of human societal self-productivity,
or of the human societal ‘‘‘self-force’’’ of the self-expanding
self-reproduction of human society.
In
this passage, Marx attributes the cause of capitalist crises -- with their concomitant
“destruction”, “depreciation”, and “annihilation” of capital-value -- ultimately
to the growth of the social forces of production fostered by capital itself.
Marx
does not make explicit the detailed mechanism(s) of this “destruction”,
“depreciation”, and “annihilation” in this passage, except in that, once a
crisis breaks out, “momentaneous suspension” of much of
production, and of much of the social economic process as a whole, at least
furthers this “destruction”, “depreciation”, and “annihilation” of
capital-value.
¿But could there be a connection, in
Marx’s theory, and in reality, between ongoing, gradual productive force growth
induced ‘technodepreciation’
of capital-value, and aperiodic capitalist crises, with their sudden and
intensified manifestation of capital-value “destruction”?
The
passage above does not even explicitly address, let alone answer, this question.
But
it does, at least from our point of view, implicitly pose this question.
Let
us therefore consider some other passages, in which Marx more closely verges
upon our question, and upon its answer.
The
following passage, again from the «Grundrisse», describes
a general economic “law” of depreciation of “products” values in general, as a
consequence of the growth of social productivity/of “the social forces of
production”, without yet explicitly applying this “law” to the “capital”
species of value --
“... the general economic law [is]
that the costs of production
constantly decline, that living labor becomes constantly more productive,
hence that the labor time
objectified in products constantly depreciates ...”
[p. 135].
[p. 135].
[Karl Marx, Grundrisse, ibid.,
emphases added by
M.D.].
In
the next passage, the application of this law of ‘productivity-devaluation’ to capital-value is explicit --
“... The constantly ongoing devaluation of capital,
owing to the increase in the
force of production, has to be compensated ...” [p. 317].
[Karl Marx, Grundrisse, ibid.,
emphases added by
M.D.].
This
passage is in the context of describing the necessity of positive profits to
the [continued] existence of a capital-based system of human social
reproduction.
But
this passage does not explicitly address the question as to whether a growing
proportion of profit allocated to this ‘“compensation”’ of the “constantly ongoing devaluation of capital,
owing to the increase in the
force of production”, i.e., the use of a growing
proportion of profits to offset growing “write-offs” of the book value of ‘technodepreciated’ fixed capital assets
[which figure as increments of capital loss expense, netting out against
revenues, in the accounting period, and in the periodic profit/loss statement, in
which they are recognized], and, consequently, the allocation of that growing
proportion of profit away from other uses of profit, could manifest as a secular fall in the accounting
rate of profits, or as a secular
fall in the rate of return on fixed capital investments.
The
next passage is even more explicit about this “constant devaluation of the existing capital”,
caused by capital’s “increasing [of] the force of production”,
and about where, in Marx’s systematic-dialectical method of presentation of his
theory of capital[ism], the consideration of this ‘technodepreciation’ phenomenon belongs
--
“... Looked
at precisely, that is, the realization process of capital -- and money
becomes capital only through the realization process -- appears at the same
time as its devaluation process [Entwertungs-prozess], its
demonetization.”
“And this in two respects.”
“First, to the extent that capital does not increase
absolute labor-time but rather decreases the relative, necessary labor time, by increasing the force of production,
to that extent does it reduce
the costs of its own production -- in so far as it was
presupposed as a certain sum of commodities, reduces its exchange value: one part of the capital on hand is constantly devalued
owing to a decrease in the
costs of production at which it can be
reproduced; not because of a decrease in the amount of labor
objectified in it, but because of a decease in the amount of living labor which it is henceforth necessary to objectify in this specific
product.”
“This constant devaluation of the existing capital
does not belong here,
since it already presupposes capital as completed.”
“It is merely to be noted here in order to indicate how
later developments are already
contained
in the general concept of capital.
”
“Belongs in the doctrine of the concentration
and competition of capitals.” [pp.
402-403].
[Karl Marx, Grundrisse, ibid.,
emphases added by
M.D.].
This
passage perhaps explains why Marx, in the four volumes of his great treatise --
Capital, A Critique of Political Economy. --
refers to, invokes, or describes the process that we call ‘technodepreciation’ relatively rarely,
even in his vol. III
exposition of “the law of the tendency of
the rate of profit to fall”, the fatal flaw of the
capitals-system, that he himself discovered:
the process of ‘technodepreciation’
is a [world-]market-based, competition-enforced
process.
Marx’s
original method and plan for his systematic-dialectical presentation of his
dialectical, immanent critique of the capitalist-ideology-compromised science
of classical political economy, published in his first book-length exposition
of his critique of political economy, his 1859 book entitled A Contribution to the Critique of
Political Economy, called for, not four, but
six volumes, with the following titles, in
the following order --
1: Capital
2: Landed Property
3: Wage-Labor
4: the State
5: Foreign Trade
6: World Market and Crises.
The
first “volume”, entitled Capital, was to set forth “the
general concept of capital”, or of “Capital in general”.
The
phrase “presupposes capital as completed” probably refers to Marx’s view that
“later developments”, like the [world-]market-based, competition-enforced process
of ‘technodepreciation’,
could only be properly, dialectically addressed, to Marx’s “audience”, after
the presentation of “the general concept of capital” was already in place,
i.e., only after the first “volume”, Capital, had been
completed, and assimilated by Marx’s “audience”.
In
numerous passages of the «Grundrisse», and of Capital,
volumes I-IV,
where Marx characterizes certain portions of those text’s contents as
anticipating “the doctrine of the concentration and competition of capitals”, Marx
indicates that this content is to be fully developed only in the final, “World
Market and Crises”, “volume”.
But
the four volumes -- of Capital, A Critique of
Political Economy. -- that we actually have from Marx [and from Engels,
who brought volumes II
and III to readiness for
publication after Marx’s death] are all parts of just the first planned
“volume”, the “volume” entitled Capital.
So
we never got Marx’s full, systematic[-dialectical] rendition of
‘technodepreciation’, and of its connection [if any, but we hold that it would
have been the key] to capitalist crises, that “belonged” in/to the final
planned “volume”, the “volume” that was to have been entitled World
Market and Crises.
Of
all of the extant, posthumously-published manuscripts by Marx, it is the «Grundrisse»
[English translation: “Foundation”]
-- the “Foundation” draft for Marx’s entire planned “Critique of Political
Economy” -- that comes closest to providing a sketch toward all six of the
originally planned “volumes”. [It is
possible that the extant but still unpublished manuscript by Marx, entitled “The
Money System as a Whole”, might come closer still].
The
account of the capital-system’s lawful ‘‘‘evolutionary dynamics’’’ and
‘revolutionary meta-dynamics’ that Marx presents in the four volumes of Capital
does not focus on the mechanisms and processes of the enforcement of capital’s
laws by the competition among individual capitals.
Instead,
Marx presents an “inner”, “immanent”, “internal”, ‘essence-ial’,
‘concept-ual’, law-of-value logic of capital’s [meta-]dynamics, viz. --
“... Conceptually, competition is nothing other than the inner nature of capital, its essential character,
appearing in and realized as the reciprocal interaction of many capitals with one another, the inner tendency as external necessity. ...
“Capital exists and can only exist as many capitals, and its self-determination
therefore appears as their reciprocal
interaction with one another).” [pp. 413-414].
[Karl Marx, Grundrisse: Foundations of the Critique of
Political Economy (Rough Draft), translated by Martin
Nicolaus, Penguin Books [Middlesex: 1973], emphases
added by M.D.].
--
and again --
“Competition generally, this essential locomotive force of the bourgeois economy,
does not establish its laws,
but is rather their executor.”
“Unlimited competition is therefore not the presupposition for the truth of the economic laws, but
rather the consequence -- the form
of appearance in which their necessity realizes itself.”
“For the
economists to presuppose,
as does Ricardo, that unlimited
competition exists is to presuppose the full reality and realization of the bourgeois relations of production
in their [M.D.: historically-]specific and distinct character.”
“Competition therefore does not explain these laws; rather, it lets
them be seen, but does not produce them.” [p. 552].
[Karl Marx, Grundrisse: Foundations of the Critique of
Political Economy (Rough Draft), translated by Martin
Nicolaus, Penguin Books [Middlesex: 1973], emphases
added by M.D.].
Nevertheless,
all of those scruples of the systematic-dialectical method of presentation
notwithstanding, telling clues to and hints of Marx’s ultimate theory of World
Market [Competition], [Global Economic] Crisis, and the resulting Transition to
Political-Economic Democracy, are sprinkled throughout the four volumes of Capital.
Below
is a minimal sampling from them, selected with regard to the topic of this
blog-entry --
[Vol.
II]: “As the magnitude of the value and the durability of the applied fixed capital develop with
the development of the
capitalist mode of production, the lifetime of industry and of industrial capital
lengthens in each particular field of investment to a period of many years, say
ten years on average.”
“Whereas the development of fixed capital extends the
length of this life on the one hand it is shortened on the other by the continuous revolution
in the means of production,
which likewise incessantly
gains momentum with the development of the capitalist mode of production.”
“This involves a change in the means of production and the necessity of their constant
replacement, on account of moral depreciation, long before they expire physically.”
“One may assume that in the essential branches of modern industry this
life-cycle now averages ten years.”
“However we are not concerned here with the exact
figure.”
“This much is evident:
the cycle of
interconnected turnovers embracing a number of years, in which
capital is held fast by its fixed constituent part, furnishes a material basis for the
periodic crises.”
“True, periods in which capital is invested differ greatly and far
from coincide in time.”
“But a crisis always forms the starting point of large new
investments.”
“Therefore, from the point of view of society as a whole, more
or less, a new material basis
for the next turnover cycle.” [pp. 185-186].
[Karl Marx, Capital: Volume II,
International Publishers [New York: 1967] ], emphases
added by M.D.].
This
passage even connects, though it does not yet fully explicate, the phenomenon
of capitalist economic crisis and the uniquely capitalist phenomenon of ‘technodepreciation’ [“moral
depreciation”].
The
next passage connects the process of ‘technodepreciation’
with the law of the tendency of the rate of
profit to fall, but in a dual referential context, which cites the
contradictory role thereof, in both causing the fall of the general rate of
profit, and in slowing it down, but which does not delineate in detail the
differential mechanisms of this dual role --
[Vol.
III]: “Given the rate [M.D.: of profit],
the absolute increase in the mass of capital depends on its existing magnitude.
“But, on the other hand, if this magnitude is given,
the proportion of its growth, i.e., the rate of its increment, depends on the
rate of profit.”
“The increase
in the productiveness (which, moreover, we repeat, always goes hand in
hand with a depreciation of the available capital)
can directly only increase the value of existing capital if by raising the rate
of profit it increases that portion of the value of the annual product which is
reconverted into capital.”
“As concerns the productivity of labor, this can occur
(since this productivity has nothing direct to do with the value of the
existing capital) by raising the relative surplus-value, or reducing the value of the constant
capital, so that the commodities which enter the reproduction of
labor-power, or the elements
of constant capital, are cheapened.”
“Both imply a depreciation of existing capital, and both go
hand in hand with a reduction of the variable capital in relation to the
constant. Both cause a fall in the rate of profit,
and both slow it
down.” [p. 248]
[Karl Marx, Capital: Volume III,
International Publishers [New York: 1967] ], emphases
added by M.D.].
Again,
we hold that Marx’s plan would have led him to intend to detail, and thereby to
differentiate, such mechanisms of this causation, and/versus of this
‘dilatorization’, in the final, climactic “volume” -- the planned “volume” on
the World Market, on Global Competition, on Global Economic Crises, and on the
Global Revolutionary Transition to the human social system / ‘‘‘attractor’’’
beyond capitalism.
This
expectation extends even to Marx’s ‘‘‘dual’’’ expression, in volume III of Capital, of the ultimately fatal dialectical internal self-contradiction
, or ‘intra-duality’,
immanent to the capitals-system, in its most general l
formulation, in which the process and the “dynamic” of ‘technodepreciation’ inheres --
[Vol.
III]: “The contradiction, to put it in a very general way, consists in that the capitalist mode
of production involves a tendency towards the absolute development
of the productive forces, regardless of the value
and surplus-value it contains, and regardless of the social conditions under
which capitalist production takes place; while, on the other hand, its aim is to preserve the value of the
existing capital and promote its self-expansion to the highest limit
(i.e., to promote an ever more rapid growth of this value). ”
“The specific feature about it is that it uses the existing value of capital as
a means of increasing this value to the utmost. ”
“The methods by which it accomplishes this include the fall of the rate of
profit, the depreciation
of existing capital, and the development of the productive
forces of labor at the expense of already
created productive forces.” [p. 249]
[Karl Marx, Capital: Volume III, International
Publishers [New York: 1967] ], emphases
added by
M.D.].
These
contradictory, diametrically opposing tendencies of the capitals system, (1) unrestricted growth of the productive forces,
and/versus (2)
unrestricted growth of the accumulated monetary
value of the global total social capital, cannot both be
fulfilled -- as expressed [a]periodically,
in the outbreak of horribly destructive global economic crises [and wars, and
genocides, etc.], as well as ultimately,
in the global revolutionary transition to full, political-economic
democracy.
The
next passage connects what we term ‘technodepreciation’
to Marx’s theory of the progressive rise in the “organic composition” of
capital, which resides at the heart of Marx’s “inner”, “immanent”, “internal”,
‘essence-ial’, ‘concept-ual’, ‘law-of-value-logic-al’ exposition
of the capital-fatal “law of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall”, as
presented before the outer, more concrete, more detailed market-competition-mechanisms
of this law can be properly presented, e.g., in “volume” 6 --
[Vol.
IV]: “With the growth
in the proportion of constant capital to variable capital [M.D.: c/v up, i.e., growth in “the
organic composition of capital”, reflecting the progressive growth in the
“technical composition of capital”, as approximately measured by the
value-ratio c/v],
grows also the productivity of labor,
the productive forces brought
into being, with which social
labor operates.”
“As a result of this increasing productivity of labor,
however, a part of the
existing constant capital is continuously depreciated
in value, for its [M.D.: present] value
depends not on the labor-time that it cost originally, but on the labor-time
with which it can be reproduced [M.D.: presently],
and this is continuously
diminishing as the productivity of labor
grows.”
“Although, therefore, the value of the constant capital does not increase in proportion to its amount [M.D.: E.g., in
proportion to its physical mass], it increases nevertheless, because its amount increases even
more rapidly than its value
falls.”
[pp. 415-416].”
[Karl Marx, Capital: Volume IV (Theories of Surplus-Value),
Part II, Progress Publishers [Moscow: 1968] ], emphases added by
M.D.].
However,
this passage presents the ‘technodepreciation’
of the [fixed capital component of the constant
capital, especially], as a contributor to the slowing down, not to the speeding up, of the fall
in the general rate of profit on capital, at least in its formal, algebraic
presentation.
That
is, given the Marxian rate of profit formula, p.r. = s’/(c + v), and multiplying both
its numerator and its denominator by 1 in the form of (1/v) / (1/v),
we obtain an equivalent, but more revealing, expression for the Marxian rate of
profit -- more revealing with respect to the role of the “organic composition
of capital”, (c/v),
in the “algebraic causation” of the fall in the rate of profit: (s’/v) / ( (c/v) + 1 ).
That
profit-rate ratio rises
in overall magnitude if the impact of the increase in the “rate of [esp. of the
“relative”, vs. the “absolute”]
surplus-value”, (s’/v)
-- due to the growth of the societal-[self-re-]productive forces -- outdoes
the impact of the rise in the “organic/technical composition of capital”, (c/v) -- also due to
the growth of the societal-[self-re-]productive forces -- on the magnitude of
the ratio as a whole.
That
profit-rate ratio falls
in overall magnitude if the impact of the increase in the “rate of
surplus-value”, (s’/v)
-- due to the growth of the societal-[self-re-]productive force -- in the
numerator of the ratio, therefore tending to increase the magnitude of the
ratio as a whole, is outdone by the impact of the rise in the
“organic/technical composition of capital”, (c/v) -- also due to the growth of the societal-[self-re-]productive
force -- in the denominator of that ratio, thus tending to decrease the
magnitude of the ratio as a whole.
Therefore,
to the extent that ‘productive-force-increase-induced-depreciation’, or ‘technodepreciation’, of constant capital, c, ensues, it checks
the fall in the Marxian rate of profit to some degree.
There
are also several other, more “thought-concrete” passages among the four volumes
of Capital, describing the process of ‘technodepreciation’ in language closer
to that of an outer, “surface of society” description, that emphasize only one
side of the impact of that process on the profit rate as measured by capitalist
accounting practices.
These
passages emphasize the fact that write-offs of the still-unamortized book-value of “morally
depreciated” -- ‘technodepreciated’
-- fixed capital plant and equipment, in the accounting periods after the accounting period in
which the loss due
to premature retirement of plant and equipment is recognized, reducing profit for that accounting period to
some degree, and even, in some cases -- especially as the fixed capital
component of total capital increasingly predominates as a portion of total
capital -- inducing a net loss, a negative
profit, for that
accounting period, on the contrary, raises the rate of profit-return on
fixed capital value in those subsequent accounting periods, by reducing the magnitude of the denominator of that ‘‘‘rate of return
on capital invested’’’ ratio, precisely y the amount of that book-value write-off, in each subsequent accounting period.
These
passages one-sidedly ignore the one-period, write-off-induced
rate of profit fall, or loss, and emphasize only the subsequent accounting
periods’ rate of profit rise-contribution.
But,
in the “going concern” of the capitals political-economy, as Marx -- more than any other, and rightly so -- so frequently and so
rigorously emphasized, those “individual” accounting periods, in which
competition-enforced write-offs of prematurely retired -- e.g., scrapped because no longer competitive
-- fixed capital plant and equipment continue to recur, even at an
accelerating pace, and even with a rising absolute magnitude of write-off
losses, as the fixed capital composition of total capital, and the velocity of
competition-driven technological development, incarnated in new vintages of
fixed capital plant and equipment, continue to accelerate.
Such
continual writing-off of ‘technodepreciation
costs’ against profits can
amount to -- and have
amounted -- to a secular fall in the capitalistically-accounted rates of
profit, as well as the Marxian rates of profit, especially before “special
measures” -- e.g., such as the “Federal
Reserve’s” management of an historically exponential rate of
inflation, world wars, and massive “peace-time” “investments” in the unproductive-or-destructive/anti-productive “capital”
“goods” of the national-capitalist “military-industrial complexes” -- are imposed by
the capitalist ruling class.
However,
there are also a few key passages among the four volumes of Capital that
clearly emphasize the loss side of ‘technodepreciation’,
for capital, and for capitalists, including the following two --
[Vol.
IV]: “Thus Ricardo’s ruthlessness was not only scientifically
honest but also a scientific necessity from his point of view.”
“But because of this it is also quite immaterial to him
whether the advance of the
productive forces slays landed property or workers.”
“If this progress devalues the capital of the industrial bourgeoisie it is
equally welcome to him.”
“If the development of the productive power of labor halves the value of the existing
fixed capital, what does it matter, says Ricardo.”
“The productivity of
human labor has doubled.”
“Thus here is scientific honesty.”
“Ricardo’s conception is, on the whole, in the
interests of the industrial bourgeoisie, only because, and in so far
as, their interests coincide with that of production or the productive
development of human labor.”
“Where the bourgeoisie comes into conflict with this,
he is just as ruthless towards it as he is at other times toward the
proletariat and the aristocracy.” [p. 118].
[Karl Marx, Capital: Volume IV (Theories of Surplus-Value),
Part II, Progress Publishers [Moscow: 1968] ], emphases added by
M.D.].
The
passage above, in its third through fifth sentences, clearly emphasizes the
“downside” of ‘technodepreciation’
for the capitalist class, and the progress of the social productive forces as the cause
of this ‘technodepreciation’,
and, implicitly, as the necessary
core of human progress itself, both before, during, and after
the capitalist epoch.
The
passage below, the final passage for this blog-entry, even more clearly and ‘thought-concretely’,
explicates the anti-profit, loss implications of ‘technodepreciation’ for the individual capitalist --
“Suppose, a certain line of capitalist industry
produces a normal unit
of its commodity
under the following conditions: The wear and tear of fixed capital amounts to
1/2 shilling per piece; raw and auxiliary materials go into it
to the amount of 17 1/2 shillings per piece; wages, 2 shillings; surplus-value, 2
shillings at a rate of surplus-value of 100%. Total value = 22 shillings. We assume for the sake of simplicity that the
capital in this line of production has the average composition of social
capital, so that the price of production of the commodity is identical with its
value, and the profit of the capitalist with the created surplus-value. Then the cost-price of the commodity = 1/2 +
17 1/2 + 2 = 20s., the average rate of profit 2/20 = 10%,
and the price of production per piece of the commodity, like its value = 22s.”
“Suppose a machine is invented which reduces by half the living labour required per piece of the commodity,
but trebles that portion of its value
accounted for by wear and tear of the fixed capital.”
“In that case, the
calculation is: wear and tear = 1 1/2 sh.,
raw and auxiliary materials, as before, 17 1/2 sh., wages 1sh., surplus-value
1sh., total 21sh.”
“The commodity then falls 1sh.
in value; the new machine has
certainly increased the productivity of labour.”
“But the capitalist sees the
matter as follows: his cost-price is now
1 1/2 s. for wear, 17 1/2 s. for raw and auxiliary materials, 1sh. for wages,
total 20s., as before.”
“Since the [Ed.: general] rate of profit is not immediately
altered by the new machine, he will receive 10% over his
cost-price, that is, 2s.”
“The price of production,
then, remains unaltered = 20s., but is 1s. above the value.”
“For a society producing under
capitalist conditions the commodity has not cheapened.”
“The new machine is no
improvement for it.”
“The capitalist is,
therefore, not interested in
introducing it.”
“And since its introduction would make his present,
not as yet worn-out,
machinery simply worthless,
would turn it into scrap-iron, hence would cause a POSITIVE LOSS, he takes good
care not to commit this, what is for him a utopian mistake.”
“The law of increased productivity of
labour is not,
therefore, absolutely valid for capital.”
“So far as capital is
concerned, productiveness
does not increase through a saving in living labour in general, but only through a saving
in the paid portion of living labour, as compared to labour expended in the past, as
we have already indicated in passing in Book I ... [M.D.: for this, see English edition, Capital
I, Ch. XV, 2, pp. 392-393].”
“Here the capitalist mode of production is
beset with another CONTRADICTION.”
“Its historical mission is unconstrained development in geometrical
progression of the productivity of human labour.”
“It goes back on its
mission whenever, as here, it CHECKS
the development of productivity.”
“It thus demonstrates again that it is
becoming senile and that it is more and more OUTLIVED.”
[Karl Marx, Capital,
volume III, The Process of
Capitalist Production as a Whole, International Publishers Co., Inc.
[NY: 1967], pp. 261-262 bold italic
shadowed underlined and CAPITALIZED emphasis
and square-bracket parenthetical inserts added by M.D.].
The
eleventh text-unit of the passage above makes the periodic
profit-rate-reducing, loss exacerbating side of ‘technodepreciation’ explicitly clear, for its --
essentially generic or universal -- hypothetical case.
¿So, could ‘technodepreciation-induced secular fall in
the industrial capital rate of profit’ represent the
“outer”, [world-]market/competition-enforced, expression of the --
(s’/v) / ( (c/v) + 1 )
-- ‘relative-dearth-of-living-labor[ v]-as-sole-source-of-profit-sourcing-surplus-value’, “inner”, expression of the induction of “the tendency of the rate of profit to fall”?
(s’/v) / ( (c/v) + 1 )
-- ‘relative-dearth-of-living-labor[ v]-as-sole-source-of-profit-sourcing-surplus-value’, “inner”, expression of the induction of “the tendency of the rate of profit to fall”?
¿Could the ‘technodepreciation’ of, and the
consequent scrapping/write-off of, fixed-capital plant and equipment of --
especially of advanced-technology-embodying fixed capital -- be the ‘“outer face”’
of an ‘“inner face”’ of the “law of the tendency of the rate of profit to
fall”, expressed by the ‘growing relative
depletion of surplus-value producing living labor’ in the production mix,
reflected in the growth of the ‘‘‘technical/organic composition of capital’’’,
reflected in the rising magnitude of the (c/v)
ratio?
¿Could the vanishing of the capital-value of accumulated but obsolete fixed capital be the
“outer” expression of the relative
vanishing of living workers as a component of industrial productive capital
as the “inner” expression, of the ‘self-braking’ of the rate of capital
accumulation, originally expressed as a secular fall in the rate of profit on
industrial capital? . . .”
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments here are subject to pre-publication moderation.